Monthly Archives: February 2015

The IEA’s central projections for renewables continue to look way too low

The IEA’s projections for wind and solar capacity look much too low, continuing a history of vastly underestimating renewables growth.  Their projections are not a reliable basis for projecting the world’s future power generation mix. 

I previously looked at the IEA’s track record of underestimating the growth of renewables by a huge margin.  Since then the 2013 and 2014 World Energy Outlooks have been published, and it seems timely to ask how the credibility of their outlook has improved.   The answer appears, regrettably, to be “not much”.

The chart below shows the IEA’s long term projections for global capacity additions of wind and solar PV, taken from the current version of its central New Policies Scenario, and compares these with historical growth and short term projections.  The short term projections are likely to be quite accurate, especially for wind, as projects due on this year or next are usually already in progress.

Annual net global installations of wind and solar:  comparison of IEA long term projections (New Policies Scenario) with historical data (to 2014) and short term projections (2015-6)

installation rates corrected

Notes:  Historical data is from BP, the Global Wind Energy Council and Bloomberg.  Short term projections are from Bloomberg, as of February 2015.  Long term projections are from the IEA World Energy Outlook, 2014, New Policies Scenario.  IEA projections are for 2012-2020 and for each 5 years thereafter, and are shown at the mid-point of each interval. (The original post contained a minor plotting error for some of the historic data, now corrected.  The change reinforces the story as it correctly emphasises further the rapid growth of solar.)

The historic and short term forecast data shows a clear and strong upward trend in the rate of capacity installation for both technologies, although for wind this has somewhat moderated in recent years, and there has been considerable year to year policy-driven volatility.

The IEA’s projections show a sharp reversal of this trend, with net installation rates falling to well below current levels, and staying there or falling further for the next two and a half decades.  The average annual installation rate projected by the IEA over the period 2020-2040 is nearly 30% below last year’s outturn for wind, and nearly 40% below what’s likely to be put in this year.  For solar PV the decrease is even greater, with projected installation rates 40% below last year’s outturn, and nearly 50% below what’s likely this year.  This implies a substantial contraction in the wind and solar PV industries from their present size, rather than continuing growth or stabilisation.  The IEA projects correspondingly small proportions of the world’s electricity generation coming from wind and solar PV.  Even a quarter century from now their projections show wind accounting for only 8.3% of generation (in TWh) and solar PV a mere 3.2%.

It may well be that renewables installation rates begin to grow more slowly and even eventually plateau as markets mature.  But a sudden fall by around a third or a half of current levels sustained into the long term seems to run against the main prevailing drivers.

The imperative to reduce carbon emissions from power generation is ever greater.  This looks likely to continue to be a strong driver for renewables growth through direct mandates for renewables and (especially in the long term) through incentives from carbon pricing.  Renewables are also highly compatible with other policy objectives such as security of energy supply.

Renewables are much more cost competitive than they were, both with other low carbon generation and with conventional fossil fuels, especially if fossil generation includes the cost of its emissions.  Costs for wind and especially solar are expected to continue to fall.

Some argue that the total subsidy needed by solar and wind will limit their growth.  However as costs fall any remaining subsidies required will continue to fall even faster in percentage terms (so for example a 20% decrease in costs may lead to a 50% decrease in required subsidy).  This is likely to limit the total additional costs of renewables even as volumes grow, and especially in the 2020s and 2030s as the proportion of projects requiring no subsidy grows ever greater.

There is also scope to increase the installed base of renewables globally to well above the levels projected by the IEA without causing significant problems for grid integration.  In any case such obstacles are likely to reduce over time with improved grid management, greater interconnection, and falling costs of batteries.

Given these drivers the IEA’s projections appear to be close to or below the bottom end of the credible range for rates of deployment, especially for solar, rather than the central case they are intended to represent.  They do not form a reliable basis for assessing the future of the world’s power generation mix.

Adam Whitmore – 27th February 2015

Randomised trials of energy efficiency policy

Greater use of randomised trials could help the uptake of energy efficiency by identifying which policy interventions work best.

More efficient use of energy is high on almost everyone’s list of good ways to reduce CO2 emissions.  It can lead to large scale emissions reductions, is often cost-effective, and tends to be highly compatible with other policy goals such as energy security.

Efficiency standards for buildings, vehicles and appliances have played a critical role in improving energy efficiency, and will continue to do so.  But standards are not the whole story.  Rates of uptake of more efficient technology and processes and other changes in consumers’ behaviour can matter greatly.

However it is often impossible to know in advance how innovative policy interventions will affect behaviour.   Consumers’ responses to novelty are unpredictable, and judging likely response is further complicated because consumers’ circumstances are often complex and varied.  Even afterwards it may be difficult to judge whether an intervention has been effective because it’s impossible to say what would have happened otherwise.

Fortunately there are models from elsewhere that can help address these issues.  A well proven means of judging the effectiveness of interventions is the use of randomised trials, in which one group is subject to an intervention and a similar control group is not.  These trials look to avoid biases such as self-selection, for example where those most interested in something may participate disproportionately.

Double blind randomised control trials for new drugs form a benchmark for such tests.  This approach requires two groups to be chosen differing only in whether they have a new drug or a placebo, with neither the patient nor the physician being aware who is getting which.  Provided that all such studies of each new drug are published – a controversial area – there are two comparable groups, and valid statistical inferences can be drawn about whether the drug has been effective.

The double blind element of medical treatments is not always easy to reproduce in other fields, but the use of controlled trials is common in other areas.  Technology companies often roll out two different versions of software online to subsets of users to see which gets the best response, as measured for example by click-through rates.    This approach allows decisions to be data driven rather than based on judgement or experience.  Tests on users may be ethically controversial, as Facebook found with experiments to its news feeds.  And outcomes are not always desirable from the consumer’s point of view, for example when an option to turn down an offer is less visible on screen, even if few people want the offer.  But effectiveness will likely have been demonstrated, at least for major websites.

Development organisations have used similar approaches in looking at uptake, for example testing different ways of increasing uptake of immunisation programmes [1].

Data driven decision making of this sort is often contrasted with traditional decision making based on the judgement of someone senior, which is sometimes referred to as HIPPO based decision making (Highest Paid Person’s Opinion).  It also goes beyond a vague requirement for evidence based policy making, in that it requires a certain type of evidence to be gathered.  This reduces the often-noted risk that evidence based policy-making turns into policy based evidence-making.

Controlled trials are now beginning to be used to test interventions designed to increase energy efficiency.  In a trial in Norway [2] the labelling of appliances was changed to make it more meaningful to consumers.  Labels in some stores showed lifetime electricity running costs and improved staff training while the control groups had labelling showing only annual kWh and no training.  For fridge-freezers no significant effect was found. For tumble dryers the combined label and training reduced average energy use of tumble dryers sold by 4.9% while training alone led to a 3.4% reduction. The effect was strongest initially, but declined over time.

A similar change of labelling was undertaken in the UK in a joint study by John Lewis department stores working in collaboration with the Department of Energy and Climate Change (DECC) [3].  A statistically significant but small effect (0.7% increase in efficiency of appliances sold) was observed.  Another, earlier, study on interventions for households with difficulties affording enough energy found no reduction in bills, but an increase in comfort [4].

It is encouraging to find such approaches beginning to be adopted.  However they appear to remain very much the exception not the norm.  There are many other areas where such trials could make a large contribution.  Smart metering in particular could benefit from this.  There are many options for both design and use of smart meters.  It is far from clear which will work best.  Trials are needed to find out.  Although there have been a few such studies [5] many more are needed.

Such trials are not as cheap or easy as making a judgement about what will work and hoping for the best.  And they represent a high hurdle for interventions to clear.  But they are more robust as a result, and should lead to more effective (and cost-effective) outcomes.  Controlled trials need to become more widespread if energy efficiency is to make a full contribution to reducing emissions.

Adam Whitmore – 10th February 2015

Notes:

[1]  The use of controlled trials to look at poverty alleviation and development is described (among other topics) by Abhijit Vinayak Banerjee and Esther Duflo in their book Poor Economics and more concisely and relevantly by Duflo in the accompanying TED talk.

[2] Kallbekken et al. “Bridging the Energy Efficiency Gap: A Field Experiment on Lifetime Energy Costs and Household Appliances” Journal of Consumer Policy, 2013  http://link.springer.com/article/10.1007%2Fs10603-012-9211-z#page-1

[3] https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/evaluation-of-the-decc-and-john-lewis-energy-labelling-trial

[4] http://eprints.hud.ac.uk/9489/1/Microsoft_Word_-_Pragmatic_randomised_controlled_trial_of_a_fuel_poverty_intervention__Heyman_et_al_.pdf

[5] See for example:

http://www.ieadsm.org/Files/Content/Goette.pdf

Click to access energy-demand-research-project-final-analysis.pdf

https://ideas.repec.org/a/eee/eneeco/v45y2014icp234-243.html